A Change of Guard

សូមស្តាប់វិទ្យុសង្គ្រោះជាតិ Please read more Khmer news and listen to CNRP Radio at National Rescue Party. សូមស្តាប់វីទ្យុខ្មែរប៉ុស្តិ៍/Khmer Post Radio.
Follow Khmerization on Facebook/តាមដានខ្មែរូបនីយកម្មតាម Facebook: https://www.facebook.com/khmerization.khmerican

Sunday 3 July 2016

The political economy of land grabs in China and India


21 November 2015 EAF
Author: Lynette H. Ong, University of Toronto

A farmer makes his way back home in the village of Wuwei, Anhui Province, July 2002. A full 20 years after the late patriarch Deng Xiaoping pushed through the decollectivisation of China's countryside, farmers in the rural reform laboratory of Anhui province say working the land alone is not enough for them to survive. (Photo: AAP).

Behind the impressive growth of the world’s two largest emerging nations, China and India, land has been a key infrastructural resource as well as a major source of social conflicts. Laws in both countries have allowed the governments to take land away from agricultural communities for industrialisation and development, while offering little compensation or no resettlement alternative in return.

A farmer makes his way back home in the village of Wuwei, Anhui Province, July 2002. A full 20 years after the late patriarch Deng Xiaoping pushed through the decollectivisation of China's countryside, farmers in the rural reform laboratory of Anhui province say working the land alone is not enough for them to survive. (Photo: AAP).

Farmers are typically poorly compensated. Compensation is inadequate to offset the ceding of permanent rights or is not reflective of future asset value once land is sold to private interests. Social discontent associated with land acquisition is also fuelled by popular perceptions of rampant corruption and governments’ collusion with real estate developers.

What explains this similarly anti-farmer outcome in the two countries with such distinctively different political systems — China being a one-party authoritarian state while India is a multiparty democracy?



Granted, the two countries had different starting points in recent times. When the Chinese Communist Party ruled China in 1949, it introduced a land reform where rural land was violently taken from landlords and redistributed to landless peasants. Collectivised farming was introduced.

While land became more equitably distributed among rural households in post-1949 China, India had never seen any comprehensive land reform, except in the former socialist states of Kerala and West Bengal. Despite the abolition of the zamindari system — in which an aristocratic class owned and collected taxes on large areas of land — and introduction of a land ceiling law after independence, India still has a highly fragmented land-holding system, ranging from large and medium-sized landlords, to small and marginal landholders and landless peasants. Marginal identity groups, such as the Dalits and Other Backward Castes tend to be over-represented among the marginal landholders and the landless.

India also has more varied regional outcomes in land resistance. They range from strident and successful resistance in Goa and West Bengal, to relative lack of dissonance in Gujarat and Tamil Nadu and anywhere in between. When the giant industrial group, Tata, was booted out of West Bengal after its car plant proposal was rejected by farmers whose land was affected, Modi’s government in Gujarat welcomed it with open arms.

Despite political centralisation, the central autocrats in China ensure local government’s pursuance of economic growth by instituting political and fiscal incentives that prioritise growth and revenue collection — above other social development indicators.

Fiscal reform in 1994 that recentralised a wide range of revenue, while leaving expenditure assignments unchanged, has left local governments scrambling for income. Land-leasing income has since emerged to be the single largest revenue for municipal and local governments. Additionally, the cadre evaluation system, the means by which local party officials are assessed and on which their promotion depend, features fiscal revenue as a priority target.

Chinese land law does not allow farmers to sell land directly to private developers. China has a dual land regime where rural land is collectively owned, while urban land is state-owned. Local governments are the essential middleman that has the power to requisition collective-owned land from farmers, convert it to state ownership and then sell user-rights to private real estate developers. This provides huge space for rent-seeking behaviour by local governments to buy low and sell high. All these institutions discriminate against agricultural communities and result in highly exploitative outcomes for farmers

In India, while the central laws form the basis of land acquisition, state governments have considerable autonomy to shape land policies in their jurisdictions. The Special Economic Zone Act 2005 — largely inspired by the success of the export-oriented industries in China — opened up a new avenue for state acquisition of land. Land acquired for this avenue has triggered a spate of land-related protests in recent years.

While the Indian fiscal system is relatively centralised, economic liberalisation since the 1990s — specifically the abolition of central licensing — has spurred regional competition among state governments for investment. Cheap land, along with various tax and non-tax incentives, is offered as a carrot to court investors. State governments often step in to acquire land on behalf of private investors, invoking the ‘eminent domain’ clause. The frenzy of land grabs in India is driven by electoral imperative, as economic growth and job creations matter greatly for state politicians.

Local political economy structures, particularly the extent to which the dominant castes have diversified out of agriculture and are willing to part with agricultural land, largely explain the varied land politics outcomes in India. Caste-based mobilisations in social resistance and in electoral support for regional parties weigh heavily on regional patterns of land liberalisation.

The business-friendly Gujarat, with the dominant Kanbi-Patidars caste, long diversified into agro-businesses as opposed to the agricultural smallholders-dominated West Bengal. These offer prime examples of how the local political economy and identity politics can meet to shape regional land outcomes.

Lynette Ong is an associate professor in the department of political science and the Munk School of Global Affairs at the University of Toronto. Follow her on twitter @onglynette. This article was originally published here by Policy Forum.

2 comments:

Anonymous said...

china has a very big problem on her own... the country has 3 trillion dollars in corporate bonds ( money borrowed to invest/function ) and some corporations are now broke ( not able to pay dividend /interest on those bonds )-- one can begin to see in cambodia where factory just shut its door and leave with no notice ; chinese gov or central will have to step in or their economy will implode...and out of work people will begin another revolution , something chinese gov is very worried about. By the way after the brexit vote , stocks went down and just as predicted central banks came to the rescue and injected plenty of money through banks in the US the central bank henchmen are called the PPT ( plunge protection team , created during Reagan 's years) ; after all they can't have the elites losing wealth ( in billions in just a few days ) .. now it is all well again for the elites.

Anonymous said...

ditto. Thx.